The Implementation Gap, Part II
...continued from Part I....
(citations by Golooba-Mutebi, 2012 unless otherwise noted)
Golooba-Mutebi goes on to list many
examples of poor implementation efforts in Uganda and Rwanda, which however can
likely be seen as universal problems that occur in many environments with
similar conditions. One of these is that both recently expanded institutions and
private actors simply lack “the capacity, the experience and the organisational
sophistication” for their jobs. District officials, as in Masaka district, are
hopelessly overstretched and mismanaged to the point where they frequently give
up on carrying out their jobs properly, resulting in a failure to carry out
repairs on damaged infrastructure and a lack of supervision of other actors,
with cascading effects.
Due lack of supervision,
government, community and private actors lack the incentive to likewise carry out
their function appropriately. In the profit-oriented private sector this is particularly
problematic, where contractors would “cheat on parts and carry out incomplete
installations, whereas in other cases, they use second-hand rather than the
expected new parts.” Also, contracts are often given out to firms without the
necessary qualifications as there is no proper evaluation process for bids. In many
water user committees, the absence of penalties means water users lie that they
cannot afford paying any contributions, committee bank accounts are
non-existent, and volunteers don’t carry out their functions as no one checks
whether they do. Government officials often do not keep to water quality testing
guidelines and only perform quality checks when there is very strong evidence
that a source is contaminated.
Local leaders who are made responsible for
certain enforcement tasks frequently face an obvious conflict of interests since they
are democratically elected, and so “have not been able consistently to enforce
bye-laws because they fear antagonising potential voters […] who may in turn
vote them out of office.” User committee members are often also elected, and
face a similar situation since “those who have attempted to enforce regulations
face hostility from their neighbours.” While Rwanda has taken steps to resolve
these conflicts of interest, the situation is common in Uganda.
Irrelevance of Politics?
Irrelevance of Politics?
Though these are all problems that are only
partially resolved, Golooba-Mutebi carries on to describe how in Nyamagabe
district, Rwanda, water supply management has improved significantly more than
in Masaka district, Uganda. The reasons he holds responsible for these
improvements are just as interesting and ‘non-ideological’ as the ones he says
are at the root of the problems: “the generally high quality provision is the
outcome of the all-important co-ordination and oversight functions of local
authorities, which they perform with ample commitment and diligence. The local
authorities’ commitment itself stems from active oversight and intervention
from the central state that imposes strict regular reporting requirements. No
actor transacts their business in ways that render the delivery of safe water
impossible or unnecessarily difficult.” Furthermore, he praises Rwanda
“removing user committees operating on the basis of voluntarism and associated
problems from the equation,” to replace them with representatives that are
supervised, receive compensation and have the time to carry out their roles
adequately.
Golooba-Mutebi paints an uncomfortable but
realistic picture on the role of politics and ideology in water supply
management. While I feel many researchers partially recognise these problems, I
have not seen them addressed (or perhaps admitted?) so clearly by anyone else.
To resolve these issues, according to him, would mean that the
political debate, sadly, is not a debate relevant to most users of domestic
water. It is detached, and although relevant morally and in relation to the
environment, it is not a debate that brings ordinary people closer to access of
safe and plentiful water.
General attention, investment and aid must
turn to closing enforcement gaps, balancing responsibilities and encouraging
cooperation and democratisation. Water supply should not be framed as a political
problem but as a problem of execution, from which the entire political debate
should be isolated, and that improved execution would result in projects from
all sorts of interest groups (private company, government institution, NGO,
academics) achieving much more success.
Does this, however, mean that measures
preventing inequalities are shifted to a lesser position within domestic water
supply management? Interestingly, in his 2005 paper Pieter van der Zaag
reflects that “in my own country, the Netherlands, they say that democracy was
like a by-product of our water management institutions, the waterschappen. Water management taught
us the importance of inclusive and democratic decision-processes.” Thus, will
dysfunctional water management always prevent inclusive and democratic IWRM
values from succeeding, while at the same time functional water management will
automatically lead to more fairness and stakeholder representation? Similarities
can even be drawn to Michael Foucault’s influential description of the
‘disciplinary society’, where he argues modern society functions through
ordinary citizens contributing to governance by simply being capable of
observing other members of society carrying out their assigned functions.
Conclusion
So, after all these posts and after coming
full circle it is time to share some concluding thoughts on the topic of Water, Politics and Africa. From my
first post it was clear to me that the problems of domestic water supply management
continue to be very severe, with population continually rising and resources
being ever more stretched. I then covered the debate on water supply management
in the way it is most often framed by nearly everyone involved: “the market, the
government, or the community?” This debate is unresolved, and both researchers
and organisations continually bring out new ‘mixes’ of the three, including IWRM.
But Golooba-Mutebi takes a step back, and in his eye-opening paper suggests
that it is not this ‘mix’ that is wrong, but that the implementation gap
between ideology and reality is not being addressed effectively. I must agree
with his point of view, as it simply seems most realistic and logical. It
explains perfectly well why similar projects succeed in one area but completely fail
in another, and explains what Kate Bayliss had to say on privatisation, covered
in earlier posts.
Source |
But are things going to change? Do
researchers, mostly from the West, have an interest in the political debate on
water management being replaced by an implementation debate where, since the latter
relies much more on knowledge of local culture and social organisation rather
than an academic knowledge of economics, political systems, climate
change and international organisations? Probably not. Do international corporations,
NGOs and career politicians want to be told that it is not them with their
investments, ideas and projects that are making a difference, but the low-level officials
who make sure money ends up where it is supposed to? Probably not. Established
systems are good at sustaining themselves, which I’m sure everyone can agree is
not always a good thing, but hopefully this blog has for you, as it has for me,
stimulated some thought and got you to critically think about some of the
established ways of doing things, which although probably won’t change the
world is a pretty good achievement for one little blog.
Thank you for reading and all the best,
Arnold
Comments
Post a Comment